The current understanding of economic development has evolved significantly over the last six decades. From the 1950s' emphasis on investment in physical capital, the theory has expanded to include the influence of institutions—both ‘hardware’ and ‘software’—that shape a country’s development environment.
According to Jinghan Chen, the environment surrounding development—especially FDI—is critical. However, even when all potential conditions are present, growth depends on how well the economy is managed. Appropriate state policies are essential to convert potential growth into actual development outcomes.
The role of the State in manipulating market forces has been debated since Adam Smith and the concept of the “invisible hand.” Yet, practical realities in developing economies demand a more interventionist approach.
1) Ignorance and Lack of Information: Especially for long-term, lumpy capital investments, market participants often lack sufficient data to make optimal decisions.
2) Obstacles and Bottlenecks: Market prices alone cannot manage the structural impediments in developing economies. Only state-administered changes can address these issues effectively.
3) Inadequacy of Social Overhead Capital (SOC): The State must invest in foundational infrastructure to enable private sector productivity.
4) Divergence Between Social Costs and Benefits: Markets ignore externalities. The State can correct this through taxes, subsidies, regulation, or legal frameworks.
5) Environmental Concerns: Markets fail to internalize environmental costs. The State must enforce sustainability to protect natural resources and future generations.
6) Monetary Control: Only the State can ensure a stable banking and monetary system to mobilize savings and control credit according to national needs.
7) Mobilisation of Resources: Mobilizing domestic and foreign resources on a national scale is beyond the private sector's capacity—this is a State function.
8) Skill Formation: Skill development, essential for growth, requires public investment in education and services infrastructure.
9) Balanced Development: Only the State can coordinate sectors like agriculture, industry, and services for equitable development.
10) Poverty and Deprivation: The State has a paternal role in ensuring basic rights such as education and healthcare, and must also legislate against socially harmful activities like drug and alcohol abuse.
11) Welfare State Function: The modern State must actively reduce inequalities via land and property reforms, employment generation, and worker participation in industry management.
In essence, the modern State is considered an indispensable instrument of economic development. It compensates for market failures and overcomes the myopic tendencies of markets that often fail to allocate investment efficiently over time.
East Asian success stories illustrate how governments—through stable macroeconomic environments, legal institutions, skilled human capital, and targeted rent allocation—have guided market-driven growth. Similar patterns were observed in the United States during its developmental stages, reinforcing the vital role of government involvement in economic transformation.
The debate in development economics is no longer about whether the State should intervene, but how much and in what form. A modern State plays four broad roles: regulatory, promotional, entrepreneurial, and planning.
The State exercises control over:
Entry into specific business sectors utilizing public facilities or scarce resources.
Operational conduct of industries via legislation and management standards.
Accrual and allocation of business income.
Relationships among economic interest groups to ensure rights and resolve disputes.
Environmental protection from industrial degradation.
The government promotes public welfare by:
Enhancing education and technology.
Supporting the financial sector.
Investing in infrastructure.
Establishing a social safety net for vulnerable populations.
The State participates directly in economic activities through public ownership and management of industrial and commercial enterprises.
Involves the allocation of scarce resources in line with national priorities. Planning compensates for the price mechanism's inability to ensure equitable and efficient growth.
Economic planning peaked in the 1950s and early 1960s when most developing nations adopted Five-Year Plans, often encouraged by aid donors and institutions like the World Bank. But by the 1970s, global economic crises, stagflation, and stagnating growth disillusioned many with planning. These events led to the recognition of government failure.
i) Individuals typically know their own needs better than the government does.
ii) Uniform plans may expose the entire economy to systemic risks.
iii) Government plans often suffer from rigidity and bureaucratic complexity.
iv) Governments may lack administrative capacity to implement detailed plans effectively.
v) Excessive controls discourage private sector initiative.
vi) Public systems often lack incentives for innovation, efficiency, and cost control.
vii) Poor coordination among levels of government limits effectiveness, especially in diverse regions.
viii) Informal sectors and black markets undermine rationing and pricing policies.
ix) Rent-seeking and corruption arise as interest groups seek to exploit government controls.
x) Privileged groups may manipulate plans for self-interest, creating entrenched power structures.
xi) Narrow political interests may dominate planning, undermining national welfare.
xii) Governments often fail to “pick winners” in technology. Notable failures include:
Japan’s failed investment in mainframe computing.
EU’s misjudged investments in high-definition television.
Such decisions are better left to private sector managers with market discipline.
The debate on the role of the state versus the market began in the early 1970s and has led to some important conclusions:
A system of detailed central planning in a large, diversified economy is counterproductive.
Market forces, when free from excessive government interference, are essential for promoting economic growth and efficient resource allocation.
At one point, state intervention began to attract scorn. As The Economist put it, this disdain was akin to someone “playing a 75 rpm record with 1920s music at a party.” It was termed a “bloodless revolution.”
However, this faith in markets alone was short-lived. The 2008–09 global financial crisis exposed both state failure and market failure, shaking the core of the free-market paradigm.
It became clear that free markets were not solving problems of poverty or development, particularly in underdeveloped countries (UDCs), where market foundations are weak. Many peasants and the poor did not benefit from the economic reforms of the 1980s and 1990s.
Thus emerged a consensus that state and market must work in a complementary manner, each supplementing the other to avoid “government excesses” and ensure more equitable distribution of economic gains. The aim is to maximize public welfare while satisfying the interests of all economic players — consumers, producers, traders, wage-earners, and non-wage earners.
As we progress into the 21st century, state intervention is becoming increasingly assertive and relevant due to growing economic challenges.
Addressing market failure through the provision of public goods like:
Defence
Law and order
Property rights
Macroeconomic management
Public health
Improving equity by protecting the poor through:
Anti-poverty programmes
Disaster relief
Addressing externalities such as:
Basic education
Environmental protection
Regulating monopolies via:
Utility regulation
Anti-trust policy
Overcoming imperfect social information through:
Financial regulation
Consumer insurance
Providing insurance such as:
Redistributive pensions
Unemployment benefits
Coordinating private activities through:
Fostering markets
Cluster initiatives
Undertaking asset redistribution
The debate continues as we move through the new millennium. As Deepak Nayyar notes, “We have not yet reached the end of the history.” The view that neither the market nor planning is complete or mutually exclusive has gained appeal.
The respective roles of the state and the market should be based on the comparative advantages of each. Their relationship should be supportive and non-antagonistic.
Much of India’s economic growth in the early 21st century can be attributed to the pro-growth role of the government. Historical analysis of global growth episodes supports the idea that the state must play a central role in long-term development strategies.
Efforts are underway to ensure that the state's role remains constructive and facilitative, not a hindrance to progress.